Environmentalism, public choice and the railways

Richard Wellings

Originally published in The Railways, the Market and the Government (IEA, 2006).

Introduction

Although accounting for under one tenth of passenger and freight mileage, the railways will receive over one third of the expenditure earmarked in the government’s revised Ten Year Transport Plan (DETR, 2000; DfT, 2004; ORR, 2006, 32-35). It can be argued that rail’s prominent role to a significant extent results from the belief among policy-makers that it is a more environmentally acceptable mode of transport than the private motor vehicle. The aim of this chapter is therefore to examine the part played by environmentalism in shaping the government’s railway strategy.

It is contended that during the 1990s environmental interests managed to exert significant influence on the transport policy of the UK government. Accordingly, the fuel duty escalator was introduced, the road construction programme was cut dramatically and a new emphasis was placed on supporting public transport. Congestion problems would no longer be solved by expanding the road network. Instead, a combination of incentives and subsidies would be deployed in order to encourage individuals to use public transport rather than private cars.

The change in emphasis began under the Conservative administration in the first half of the 1990s. However, apart from an increase in rail subsidies to facilitate the privatisation process, spending on public transport was not raised significantly in response to the large cuts in the road programme (Department of Transport, 1997).

The election of a Labour government in 1997 hastened the shift to a “greener” policy. The Department of Transport was merged with the Department of the Environment in order to ensure that environmental concerns played a more important role in policy development. An integrated transport system was promised in the 1998 White Paper, A New Deal for Transport: Better for Everyone, and environmentalism was a key rationale for the measures advocated.

“The effect of noise and pollution is damaging people’s health and the quality of life in towns and cities. The countryside is being eroded and we are damaging the wider environment, even changing our planet’s climate. A consensus for radical change in transport policy has emerged…We cannot go on as we were, trying to build more and more new roads to cope with growing levels of traffic.”

(Department of the Environment, Transport and the Regions, 1998, 1)

Although many of the radical measures suggested in the 1998 white paper were not implemented, in part because of opposition such as the fuel protests of September 2000, environmental objectives have provided part of the justification for recent policy decisions. The government’s Ten Year Transport Plan promised to provide a transport system that makes less impact on the environment by 2010 (Department of the Environment, Transport and the Regions, 2000, 9), while the 2004 White Paper, The Future of Transport, placed particular emphasis on reducing emissions from the transport sector in order to reduce their impact on climate change (Department for Transport, 2004).

Clearly an understanding of the growth of environmentalism in transport policy is essential to any analysis of Britain’s railways and their prominence in the government’s long term plans. This paper deploys public choice theory in the examination of the political processes that contributed to the substantial changes in transport policy over the last 15 years. Following a brief introduction to the main theoretical themes, an account is given of the strategic activities of those special interests heavily involved in the transport field and the extent to which they have been successful in influencing the development of government policy.

Public choice theory

Public choice theory provides insights into the process of policy change by focusing on the incentives facing individual political actors. It is suggested that policy is largely driven by special interests rather than the preferences of the wider general population. This tendency is the result of the logic of collective action. Members of very large ‘latent’ groups, such as motorists or taxpayers, have little incentive to get involved in political lobbying since the probability of their individual activities making any difference are so tiny (Olson, 1965). It is in their interest to ‘free-ride’ and let someone else do the work for them, since they will still receive the benefits of successful lobbying for their point of view, whether or not they actually get involved themselves. Thus motorists as a whole benefited from the freeze in fuel duty obtained by the farmers and hauliers engaging in fuel protests, even though they played no significant part in the direct action.

There are three separate factors that keep large dispersed groups from furthering their own interests. The larger the group the smaller is the fraction of the benefit accruing to the whole group that is received by any individual person who joins the action. Second, the larger the group, the lower is the likelihood that any small subset of the group or any individual will gain enough from obtaining the benefit to make it worthwhile bearing even a small amount of the burden of trying to obtain the benefit. Third, the larger the group the greater the organisation costs, and thus the higher the hurdle that must be jumped before any gains at all can be obtained (ibid.).

The logic of collective action suggests that, because of the different incentive structures facing individual members, there is a strong tendency for small concentrated interests to be able to exploit large dispersed interests in the extraction of ‘rent’ from government. Collective action problems make it extremely difficult for large dispersed interests to organise themselves into an effective lobbying organisation. Accordingly, the pattern of special interest action in any field is profoundly influenced by the logic of collective action.

One important tendency is emphasised by Stigler (1971). He suggests that, as a rule, the policy process is acquired by the industry concerned and is designed and operated primarily for its benefit at the expense of the wider public. This tendency reflects the logic of collective action described above. The industry concerned often consists of only a small number of firms whereas the public is representative of a large dispersed ‘latent’ interest for which the coordination of profitable lobbying activity is virtually impossible.

Industry interests engage in what is termed ‘rent-seeking’ behaviour, lobbying politicians and bureaucrats to introduce policies that favour their members through contracts, regulations or subsidies. According to Tullock, “investment in influencing government action appears to have high payoffs” (Tullock, 1989, 4). It might be more profitable for a company to invest a relatively small amount of money in lobbying for policies that suppress competition or increase subsidies rather than investing large capital sums in building new capacity (ibid). However, there are large variations from industry to industry in the extent to which company profits are reliant on government policy. These variations create differences in the incentive structures facing companies when they consider the funding of lobbying activities. Accordingly, it would be expected that firms whose profits are heavily dependent on government contracts, subsidies or regulations, would exhibit a much higher degree of involvement in lobbying activities than less dependent firms.

While bureaucrats may be one focus of lobbying by companies, they also constitute a special interest in themselves. They have been characterised as self-interested, deploying strategies to achieve a complex set of goals including power, income, prestige and job security (Downs, 1967). If these goals are dependent to a significant extent on the size of the bureaucracy’s budget then it will be rational for senior officials to try and maximise the financial resources under their control through a budget-maximisation strategy (Niskanen, 1971). Thus, there can be strong pressure from within government departments to increase expenditure levels. However, if the welfare of high-ranking civil servants is largely divorced from spending levels, it can be rational for them to lobby for the size of their department or agency to be reduced by “hiving-off” low-status responsibilities to other agencies, leaving small, elite, high-status institutions, primarily concerned with policy development (Dunleavy, 1991).

Whether or not the lobbying activities of special interests are successful in changing policy depends in part on the decisions of politicians. However, it is debatable to what extent their choices are based on the desire to satisfy the preferences of voters. For example, transport policy is just one issue among many and specific measures can rarely be voted on directly by an electorate. Furthermore, public choice theory suggests that rather than seeking to fulfil the wants of the electorate, both politicians and special interest groups tend to actively attempt to dictate those wants through a process of agenda manipulation (see Riker, 1993). If members of the public desire policy change then, in many instances, the perceived importance or salience of an issue reflects the way in which that issue has been covered in the media. As part of their lobbying activities and rent-seeking behaviour, special interests take advantage of the media’s power to persuade by attempting to influence coverage, creating targeted news stories and even trying to control what language is used.

The manipulation of the political agenda by special interests appears to have played an instrumental role in the growth of environmentalism’s role in transport policy. The next section therefore identifies the major organisations involved and examines the strategies that were deployed by the lobbyists from the late 1980s to the present day in order to promote a substantial shift in the government’s position.

The environmental movement

The shift to a more environmentalist transport policy followed a substantial increase in the salience of green issues in the late 1980s. The membership of both Greenpeace and Friends of the Earth (FoE) more than quadrupled between 1985 and 1989, the year when the Green Party obtained 15% of the vote in the European elections and the combined membership of environmental groups reached 4 million in the UK (Rawcliffe, 1995). Media coverage of the Chernobyl nuclear accident and issues such as acid rain, global warming and ozone depletion had clearly influenced a significant proportion of the population. Indeed, in 1988, Prime Minister Thatcher acknowledged the increasing political importance of environmental concerns, stating, in a well publicised speech, “It’s we Conservatives who are not merely friends of the Earth– we are its guardians and trustees for generations to come. The core of Tory philosophy and for the case for protecting the environment are the same” (Thatcher, 1988).

Thus, by 1990, boosted by increased memberships and closer contact with ministers and senior bureaucrats, the environmental interest groups were in a far more powerful position than they had been five years earlier. The upper echelons of the Conservative government had also undergone great upheaval with a change in leadership and arguably a shift in emphasis away from free-market economic policies. At the same time, the British economy was entering a deep recession and government borrowing was rising at an alarming rate. These particular circumstances provided favourable conditions for special interest groups to intensify their efforts to influence transport policy.

Emissions concerns

The Department of the Environment (DoE) was active in promoting the perception that further government intervention was necessary to reduce the environmental impact of the transport sector. Its 1990 White Paper, This Common Inheritance, produced under Chris Patten, identified road transport as a growing source of carbon dioxide and singled it out as a “sector out of control” (DoE, 1990, 127). The aim of bringing down UK carbon emissions to 1990 levels by 2005 was also stated (ibid.). Meanwhile, the Department of Transport was supervising an acceleration of road construction through the Roads for Prosperity programme. Thus, a conflict of interest between the two bureaucracies appeared to be developing.

Environmentalist interests then made a successful effort to introduce a new dimension to the transport debate: that of urban air pollution. In October 1990 the DoE launched a weather bulletin service which included “warnings of potentially dangerous air pollution” (the Guardian, 25.10.90). Furthermore, when announcing the initiative the DoE spokesman made an implicit link between air pollution and asthma (ibid.). These events received widespread media coverage.

The subject re-emerged in summer 1991 after Greenpeace commissioned a study on the effect of air pollution on asthma. According to the Times, the report “concluded there is a definite link between asthma and air pollution” . DoE officials were reported as considering issuing smog alerts, regulations and guidelines under headlines such as “Pollution takes toll of asthmatics” , adding legitimacy to the Greenpeace claims. Friends of the Earth provided an additional report showing “new medical evidence” on the health effects of exhaust emissions (ibid).

Further coverage came in December 1991 with headlines such as “Health Warning as Smog covers London” and “London endures worst pollution” . The apparent source of the information was once again the DoE: “The environment department, which monitors nitrogen dioxide and sulphur dioxide levels, asked the public to restrict its use of cars to reduce exhaust emissions” (ibid.)

Once ignited the salience of the air pollution issue rose dramatically, helped by targeted newspaper campaigns such as “Pollution and the Health of the Nation” in The Times and a number of pro-environmentalist BBC documentaries including Panorama’s “Battling for Air”. By April 1994 a survey by The Times revealed that nine out of ten people believed that the government must take urgent action to cut exhaust fumes to protect children from asthma. An ICM poll for the Guardian, in August 1995, found a majority of people in favour of banning cars from city centres (Rowell, 1996, 351). Media coverage appeared to have been highly successful at moulding public opinion.

Road protesters

The organised opposition to road construction schemes formed a second strategy in the attempt by environmentalist interests to influence British transport policy. Media interest in the activities of anti-road groups increased significantly following the intervention of the European Community’s Environment Commissioner, Carlo Ripa di Meana, in October 1991. The commissioner wrote to the Secretary of State for Transport, Malcolm Rifkind, warning him to block work on a number of construction projects, the most prominent being the M3 extension at Twyford Down. The UK government was accused of breaching European Community directive 85/337 on Environmental Impact Assessments.

Reports focused on the European dimension until March 1992, when coverage shifted to concentrate on direct action at the Twyford Down construction site by environmental activists. Protesters, said to be members of Friends of the Earth occupied bridges due for demolition and obstructed contractors’ bulldozers. The arrest and jailing of protesters [largely members of radical group Earth First!(UK)] kept the project in the headlines throughout summer 1992.

The manipulation of the transport debate through coverage in the media was clearly a key strategy of the radical environmental groups behind much of the direct action against road schemes. For example, Earth First! (UK) activists staged a number of media ‘events’ in order to publicise their agenda. These included attempts in the courts to classify a tree house in the path of the Hackney-M11 link road as a legal dwelling, the creation of an “independent free area” the Republic of Wanstonia on the same scheme and the unravelling of a life-sized imitation motorway on the roof of the Secretary of State for Transport’s house in North London (Wall, 1999, 76-78). Pictures of these eye-catching events often made the front pages of the newspapers, drawing significant attention to both the protesters and their political message (ibid, 76).

Similar tactics were employed by the larger, more established environmental interest groups such as Friends of the Earth, although their activities tended to be more shortlived given the threat of legal action by the Department of Transport. According to Earth First! (UK) activist Rebecca Lush, Friends of the Earth “set up this bizarre ‘we are the middle-class, we are representative of middle England’ and extremely media-obsessed camp…they used symbolism very powerfully, they used the media skilfully and stopped the works with their own tactics” (quoted in Wall, 1999, 68). In fact, because Friends of the Earth played a limited part in direct, physical attempts to prevent construction at Twyford Down (see Bryant, 1996; Wall, 1999), for example, by sabotaging equipment or creating obstacles for machinery, it might be said that their protest activities were almost entirely aimed at producing media coverage and thereby influencing the transport policy agenda.

The rail lobby

One of the most significant changes to the incentive structures facing transport interests in the last twenty years derived from the gradual commercialisation, then privatisation, of the railways. The private railway industry had been immensely influential prior to World War II. Its strength provides one explanation for Britain’s failure to build a road network comparable with its major economic competitors during the 1920s and 1930s, another explanation being the relatively strict controls on private motoring (see Plowden, 1971).

The 1990s were a time of great upheaval for the railways. The gradual privatisation of British Rail, began in 1994. Before that a long period of gradual commercialisation took place. In 1982, an organisational review divided BR into five sectors: Parcels, Freight, InterCity, Network SouthEast and Regional Railways. Management tasks were reorganised and managers became responsible for specific movements of rail traffic. Accountability of costs and revenue generated by each sector subsequently improved (Nash, 1990, 2). The 1983 Serpell Report found that only 1,630 route miles of the network (about 10%) were profitable (DTp, 1983), although it has been argued that the report took inadequate account of the contributory revenue of supposedly loss-making routes (Henshaw, 1991). Worried about costs, the government gave greater emphasis to the concept of ‘a business-led railway’. Under the ‘Organisation for Quality’ initiative all employees became responsible to a director, who in turn had control over costs and revenue (Hass-Klau, 1998, 7). By the late 1980s the railway had become a largely commercial organisation and InterCity was able to operate without a direct government subsidy (ibid.). The government began to talk openly about the prospects for privatisation. In 1992 the White Paper New Opportunities for the Railways was published (DTp, 1992), which outlined plans for franchising services and creating a company responsible for the track and station infrastructure. At this stage a number of private companies began to plan their bids for franchises. Privatisation finally began in April 1994, though it took a further three years to let all the 25 passenger franchises.

After decades of being a heavily loss making state industry the railways gradually rediscovered the profit motive. However, this profit was largely artificial in the sense that it was dependent on government subsidy under the Public Service Obligation (PSO). At the same time the viability of the railways was influenced by controls on private road transport. Expensive road fuel prices, inflated by government duty, alter the economics of travel choices in rail’s favour . Furthermore, slow and congested roads, as well as strict planning regulations that limit the geographical dispersal of housing and commercial activities, may provide further incentives for using the railways. Thus it would appear logical for a newly commercialised railway to invest in lobbying for policies which would both continue a system of rail subsidies while increasing costs for road users.

Without government intervention it was likely that many rail passenger services, particularly the heavily supported ‘Regional Railways’ operations would have had to be withdrawn and many busy commuter routes would have had to charge higher fares. One major caveat is that the railways have long suffered from high levels of bureaucratic inefficiency and expensive safety regulations that bear no rational relation to the relative safety of different transport modes. Thus the network potentially may have been far more viable than it appeared to be. There is also the contested issue of social costs, although high-speed passenger rail may produce externalities equal to or greater than road transport (for example, higher overall carbon dioxide emissions per passenger mile).

While many groups associated with railway interests contributed little to the efforts to persuade the government to introduce a more environmentalist policy, Transport 2000 (T2000), a specialist pro-public transport campaigning group founded in 1972, played an instrumental role. From its inception T2000 has had close links to railway industry. It was formed as the result of a meeting between environmental organisations and railway interests in the context of the leaking of a rail policy review which threatened a massive reduction in the network from 11,600 to 7000 miles in the interest of commercial viability (Smith, 1995, 98). From the start T2000’s most important source of finance was the British Railways Board. Offices and other services were provided by the National Union of Railwaymen (NUR) (ibid.). In the privatisation era corporate subscribers comprised firms with major stakes in public transport such as National Express, Railtrack, Stagecoach and Virgin Group. Other affiliates include a number of Trade Unions (including the RMT and ASLEF) and several local authorities. However, describing T2000 as the ‘rail lobby’ would be rather unfair given the importance of the group’s relationships with environmentalist organisations such as Friends of the Earth and bureaucratic interests within government.

Indeed, T2000 staff played an important role in the setting up of ALARM UK, the organisation coordinating the anti-roads protests, and liaised closely with its leaders from more fringe groups (Dudley & Richardson, 2001, 164). T2000 also set up the Transport Round Table, which allowed establishment bodies such as the National Trust, the Countryside Commission, and even senior elements of the Department of the Environment, to liaise informally with more radical protester groups like ALARM UK and Road Alert (ibid.). For example, at a round table meeting on December 17th 1993, discussion ensued on whether any national organisations would be able to help in the training of volunteers for non-violent direct action (ibid.). Thus it could be argued that the radical road protest movement enjoyed significant strategic and logistical support from a number of special interests, including the rail industry (albeit indirectly), established environmental lobby groups and government bureaucrats.

The anti-roads, pro-public transport coalition that had been formed also enjoyed support from within government. For example, Transport 2000 had by the early 1990s fostered close relationships with both the Department of the Environment and the Treasury. The links with the DoE developed after the departure of the economically liberal Nicholas Ridley as Secretary of State, when, in part as a result of the 1990 White Paper on Sustainable Development and the appointment of the less liberal Chris Patten, the DoE began to take a deeper interest in the environmental implications of transport policy. Transport 2000 was able to help them in relation to their statutory role of commenting on transport schemes.

Elements within the DoE also used anti-roads groups to pass information about Department of Transport (DTp) activities to the press. For example, in 1991, the DTp was planning to abolish grants for rail freight, on the basis of their perception that there were not really any significant environmental costs from road freight. One group heard of the proposal through the DoE and then informed the newspapers. The resulting media criticism resulted in the DTp not only backing away from the abolition proposal but actually expanding the rail freight grant scheme massively. The anti-roads groups also began to brief the DoE about particular road scheme proposals and the department then started to use their statutory powers to prevent certain projects being built, such as the Hereford bypass .

T2000’s relationship with the Treasury during the early 1990s was still closer than that with the DoE. The Treasury, facing a large budget deficit, liaised with T2000’s Transport Taxation Group. Accordingly, T2000 were deeply involved in the reigning back of the tax refund on company cars in the 1993 budget. The group was also consulted on the introduction of the steep fuel duty rises in the same year. Perhaps most importantly, T2000 was able to help Treasury officials justify making cuts in the road programme. Thus the group provided the Treasury with many of the arguments deployed in subsequent public spending round negotiations. Treasury consultations with T2000 on this matter began in 1993, while the major road spending cuts didn’t come to fruition until the financial year 1995/96 (the actual decision would have been finalised in late 1994).

Thus by 1994 a powerful coalition had been assembled that sought to bring about change in transport policy. Although the motives for the involvement of the Treasury may have been entirely driven by the need to make spending cuts, environmentalist arguments, implanted in the public’s consciousness by a concerted media campaign, provided a useful rationale for a decrease in road expenditure and rises in fuel duty .

The road lobby

The road lobby was in a weak position to resist the shift in policy. The main umbrella organisation for pro-roads bodies, the British Road Federation (BRF), suffered from losses in its membership during the early 1990s and pressure on its budget. In part the decline reflected the depth of the recession, which hit the construction industry (a major component of BRF membership) particularly hard. The organisation also suffered from a form of the ‘free rider’ problem identified by Olson (1965). A debate started as to whether individual companies should be members or whether their trade association should be. Many companies, particularly in the construction/material supplies sectors, decided to revert to the pre-1960s situation whereby only the trade association would be a BRF member .

The difficulty for the BRF came when these trade associations found themselves in financial difficulty. For example, the British Cement Association scaled back significantly and the Federation of Construction Engineering Companies (FCEC) was dissolved. In a sense, because of the important part the construction industry played in its funding, it can be said that the BRF was somewhat dependent on the road programme for its own financial health. The road programme fed into the profits of the construction industry, which then provided money for the lobby group.

The road lobby also suffered from a weakening of its position within the Department of Transport during the first half of the 1990s. The BRF had for several decades enjoyed a close relationship with the highway engineers of the department (Hamer, 1987). However, with the formation of the Highways Agency (HA) in April 1994, as part of the Civil Service’s Next Steps reform programme, the influence of those promoting road building declined within government. The HA, detached from the main department, was unable to defend its budget in public spending round negotiations with the Treasury and had lost one third of its employees by 1997 (weakening the influence of the highway engineers further still). Meanwhile, senior bureaucrats within the core Department of Transport were able to insulate themselves from cuts in the road programme by re-organising and taking advantage of the opportunities for career development presented by both rail privatisation and environmental measures.

A further important element in the decline of the road lobby has been the absence of a powerful motorists’ organisation. The AA (Automobile Association) and RAC (Royal Automobile Club) long ago became predominantly commercial organisations providing roadside assistance and politically weak, while newer and more radical organisations such as the Association of British Drivers were still in their infancy and did not enjoy much influence within the government or the media.

The lack of a significant motorists’ lobby, despite policy changes which have been widely regarded as ‘anti-car’, appears to be consistent with public choice theories of collective action. In contrast to the rail industry, motorists are a dispersed interest, some 30 million in number. They receive no direct payments from government but are affected by government policy. Their interests are fragmented. For example, urban motorists may hardly feel the effects of fuel duty increases if they generally use their vehicle for short journeys. Other motorists might use public transport to commute to work every day and thus be split as to where their policy interests lie. Motorists are also consumers of public services and taxpayers and thus could take a more general view of high motoring taxes (what they lose in fuel duty they might gain in income tax cuts). Because motorists are a dispersed group, the expected benefit to an individual from political lobbying (such as reduced motoring costs or less congested roads) will tend to outweigh the costs of lobbying. Any costs will be borne by the individual yet the benefits spread widely amongst a group. This gives ride to the “free rider” problem and makes effective lobbying much less likely.

Furthermore, the great majority of motorists have faced severe disincentives to engagement in direct action such as that undertaken by the radical environmentalists. In order to run a car, the motorist must have an adequate income or adequate savings. His/her prolonged involvement in direct action could have a deleterious impact on his employment. He or she is likely to face high fines and personal assets are at risk from civil action. The motorist is unlikely to qualify for legal aid and may face large legal bills.

But the lack of significant collective action by motorists does not mean this group is without political influence. The sheer number of motorists and the concomitant potential democratic power should transport become a decisive election issue (even in some marginal constituencies) arguably places significant limits on the degree to which environmentalist demands can be met through policy change .

New Labour and transport policy

The shift to a more environmentalist transport policy continued after Labour displaced the Conservatives as the party of government in May 1997. The new administration immediately imposed a moratorium on road building. The White Paper on integrated transport of August 1998, prepared by the newly merged Department of the Environment, Transport and the Regions (DETR), advocated greater integration between different transport modes, increased use of private finance for public transport and the introduction local congestion charges with the raised being spent on public transport schemes.

Although the policy proposals in part reflected the underlying egalitarian ideology shared by socialism and environmentalism (see Wildavsky, 1986), a pronounced increase in the political influence of both the environmental and public transport lobbies was discernable following the change in government. For example, T2000’s access to policy makers had improved significantly. Indeed, T2000 can be said to have been a major influence on the subsequent Roads Review, which saw almost the entire road programme halted. Accordingly, Deputy Prime Minister John Prescott’s major speech on the subject was based on documents prepared by the lobby group . The organisation was also able to float new policy ideas such as the workplace parking levy and allowing local authorities to tax non-workplace commercial parking, which were then adopted by the DETR. Accordingly, a T2000 insider wrote,

Transport 2000 is now a central player in preparing this policy and the review of the roads programme associated with it. It is co-organising two private seminars with Ministers to help policy formation on managing demand and reducing car dependence…and Stephen Joseph [Director of T2000] has been appointed to a nine-person expert panel. Assistant director Lynn Sloman has been asked to join a working group on future road safety targets.

On the railways, the government satisfied the preferences of many environmental groups with a pledge to create a Strategic Rail Authority (SRA), designed to bring about a “railway renaissance”, which the government argued had been hindered by the fragmentation of the network caused by privatisation (DETR, 1998). The formation of the SRA went some way towards fulfilling the Labour Party manifesto commitment to increase public control over the industry.

However, the publication of the 1998 DETR White Paper perhaps represented a peak in the apparent influence of environmental interests over transport policy. The Deputy Prime Minister, responsible for the DETR, was unable to obtain parliamentary time for the “integrated transport” bills to become law in the 1998/99 session. This suggests that a more environmentalist transport policy was not a key priority at the highest levels in government. Furthermore, strong pressure against some of the more radical proposals in the White Paper had been exerted on ministers by powerful corporate interests, such as the major supermarket chains , who were clearly heavily dependent on private road transport. Another factor in the failure to implement many of the DETR’s recommendations may have been a decline in the media coverage of environmental issues compared with the late 1980s and early 1990s.

By the following summer the government appeared to be retreating from the radical policy position set out in the White Paper. It was announced that £59bn was to be spent on roads over the next decade. Although no major new routes were to be completed, apart from the privately funded Birmingham Northern Relief Road, more than 100 bypasses were to be built and 360 miles of motorway widened. Furthermore, the road planning process was to be cut from an average of ten years to six (DETR, 2000). The 2000 budget also ended the fuel duty escalator and reduced vehicle excise duty for owners of small cars. The fuel protests of road hauliers and farmers in September 2000 perhaps made it still more difficult for the government to fulfill its original aim of using an array of disincentives for motorists in order to encourage more of them to use public transport. Accordingly, the relationship between environmental interest groups and the government deteriorated in the transport field as policy began to depart significantly from environmentalist objectives.

At the same time safety became the overriding priority on the railways, following the Ladbroke Grove crash of October 1999 and the Hatfield crash of October 2000. These incidents produced a very high level of media coverage, most of it highly critical of privatisation, although the number of victims was relatively small compared with the 3,500 fatalities on Britain’s roads every year. The Hatfield crash in particular, and the chaos that followed as Railtrack attempted to renew track on large sections of the network, provided an important rationale for the subsequent de facto nationalisation of the infrastructure with the creation of Network Rail in October 2001. Clearly, the short term aims of improving safety and punctuality now dominated the policy debate rather than any “rail renaissance” driven by environmental concerns. The government also began to focus on containing growing levels of public expenditure on the railways. Thus by the time the 2004 White Paper, The Future of Rail, had been published, the ambitious targets of the Strategic Rail Authority, to increase passenger traffic by 50% and freight by 80%, by 2010, had effectively been abandoned. Thus there is little chance that the railways will make even a tiny dent in road transport’s market share, or, indeed, in the UK’s Carbon Dioxide emissions. It is therefore unsurprising that environmental issues were barely mentioned in The Future of Rail.

The importance of environmentalism in British transport therefore appears to have declined for the time being. However, the concerted media based campaigns of the last twenty years have conditioned the public such that problems such as air pollution provide an easy rationale for future government intervention. Meanwhile, the environmentalist inspired expansion of the railways under Labour has created powerful commercial incentives for rent-seeking behaviour on the part of the numerous firms now reliant on substantial government subsidies for their profits from the industry. These corporate interests now include a number of multinationals including some of the largest banks (for example, through ownership of the rolling stock leasing companies). It is yet to be seen to what extent the rail lobby, reinvigorated by privatisation and high expenditure, will succeed in capturing policy, now that the influence of the environmentalists appears to have waned.

Conclusion

The recent history of British transport policy demonstrates that special interests can have a significant influence over government decision-makers. In the 1990s environmentalist interests were able to take advantage of favorable conditions, such as the high level of government debt and a weakened road lobby, to forge a coalition with bureaucrats from the Department of the Environment and the Treasury, with the aim of undermining the Department of Transport’s road programme. A concerted media campaign was launched to influence the policy agenda and persuade the general public of the negative environmental impact of private road transport. The result was a political consensus that further large scale road building was an unacceptable solution for congestion problems and that the public should be given incentives to use public transport more frequently.

After the election of a Labour government in 1997, the railways were to play an important role in the new strategy. Since road capacity effectively had been capped, railways would have to absorb many of the extra journeys resulting from economic growth in congested areas like the South-East. However, despite the ambitions of the Strategic Rail Authority, it soon became apparent that increasing capacity on the railways would be extremely expensive for the Treasury (for example, the cost of the West Coast Main Line modernisation has been estimated at £7.6 billion (Hudson, 2004)). Thus, it could be argued that concerns over expenditure levels, as well as safety, have gradually replaced environmental imperatives as the key drivers of government decision-making.

Although the extent of their influence has varied over time, the significant role of special interests in the development of transport policy provides a powerful argument against the continued high level of government involvement in the transport sector. The preferences of dispersed consumers and taxpayers may be less important to policy-makers than those of pressure groups, large companies and bureaucrats. Accordingly, it is perhaps unsurprising that there is widespread public dissatisfaction with the quality and cost of Britain’s transport infrastructure. Unfortunately, the perceived failure of rail privatisation means that the level of political control over the transport sector is likely to continue to increase in the near future, providing still greater opportunities for special interests to affect policy.

References

Bryant, B. (1996) Twyford Down: roads, campaigning and environmental law. London: E & FN Spon.

Department for Transport (2004): The Future of Transport. London: TSO.

Department for Transport (2004): The Future of Rail. London: TSO.

Department of Transport (1983): Railway finances: report of a committee chaired by Sir David Serpell. London: HMSO.

Department of Transport (1997): Transport Statistics Great Britain. London: HMSO.

Department of the Environment (1990): Department of the Environment White Paper: This Common Inheritance. London: HMSO.

Department of the Environment, Transport and the Regions (1998): A New Deal for Transport: Better for Everyone. London: HMSO.

Department of the Environment, Transport and the Regions (2000): Transport 2010: The 10 Year Plan. London: HMSO.

Downs, A. (1967): Inside Bureaucracy. Boston: Little, Brown & Co.

Dudley, G. & Richardson, J. (2001): Why Does Policy Change: Lessons from British Transport Policy 1945-99. London: Routledge.

Dunleavy, P. (1991): Democracy, bureaucracy and public choice: economic explanations in political science. London: Harvester

Hamer, M. (1987): Wheels within wheels: a study of the road lobby. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.

Hass-Klau, C. (1998): Rail privatisation: Britain and Germany compared. London: Anglo-German Foundation for the Study of Industrial Society.

Henshaw, D. (1991): The Great Railway Conspiracy. Hawes: Leading Edge.

Hudson, G. (2004): “The West Coast: in the home straight?” Modern Railways, June 2004, 52-54.

Kemp, R. (2004): Presentation to the Institution of Mechanical Engineers, discussed in Modern Railways, June 2004, 30-31.

Nash, C.A. (1990): “Rail Privatisation in Britain” Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, 27 (3), 317-322.

Niskanen, W. (1971): Bureaucracy and representative government. Chicago: Aldine

Office of Rail Regulation (2006): National Rail Trends 2005-2006: quarter one. http://www.rail-reg.gov.uk

Olson, M. (1965): The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Oxford: OUP

Plowden, W. (1971): The motor car and politics, 1896-1970. London: Bodley Head

Rawcliffe, P. (1995): “Making Inroads: Transport Policy and the British Environmental Movement”, Environment, 37, 3.

Rowell, A. (1996): Green Backlash: Global subversion of the environmental movement. London: Routledge.

Smith, J.H. (1995): The politics of environmental conflict: the case of transport in Britain

1972-1992. Unpublished PhD thesis available at University of Cambridge library.

Stigler, G. (1971): “The Theory of Economic Regulation”, Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science, 2, 3, 17.

Thatcher, M. (1988): Speech to the Conservative Party Conference, October 14, 1988, http://www.margaretthatcher.org/speeches/

Tullock, G. (1989): The Economics of Special Privilege and Rent-Seeking. Norwell, Mass.:Kluwer.

Wall, D. (1999): Earth First! and the Anti-Roads Movement. London: Routledge.

Wildavsky, A. (1986): The Rise of Radical Egalitarianism. Washington DC: AUP

Advertisements

Comments are closed.

%d bloggers like this: